In his Prolegomena (The Muqaddimah), 'Abd al-Rahman Ibn Muhammad
Ibn Khaldun al-Hadrami of Tunis (A.D. 1332-1406), commonly known as Ibn
Khaldun, laid down the foundations of different fields of knowledge, in
particular the science of civilization (al-'umran). His significant
contributions to economics, however, should place him in the history of
economic thought as a major forerunner, if not the "father," of
economics, a title which has been given to Adam Smith, whose great works
were published some three hundred and seventy years after Ibn Khaldun's
death. Not only did Ibn Khaldun plant the germinating seeds of
classical economics, whether in production, supply, or cost, but he also
pioneered in consumption, demand, and utility, the cornerstones of
modern economic theory.
Before Ibn Khaldun, Plato
and his contemporary Xenophon presented, probably for the first time in
writing, a crude account of the specialization and division of labor. On
a non-theoretical level, the ancient Egyptians used the techniques of
specialization, particularly in the era of the Eighteenth Dynasty, in
order to save time and to produce more work per hour. Following Plato,
Aristotle proposed a definition of economics and considered the use of
money in his analysis of exchange. His example of the use of a shoe for
wear and for its use in exchange was later presented by Adam Smith as
the value in use and the value in exchange. Another aspect of economic
thought before Ibn Khaldun was that of the Scholastics and of the
Canonites, who proposed placing economics within the framework of laws
based on religious and moral perceptions for the good of all human
beings. Therefore all economic activities were to be undertaken in
accordance with such laws.
Ibn Khaldun was
cognizant of these ideas, including the one relating to religious and
moral perceptions. The relationship between moral and religious
principles on one hand and good government on the other is effectively
expounded in his citation and discussion of Tahir Ibn al-Husayn's (A.D.
775-822) famous letter to his son 'Abdallah, who ruled Khurasan with his
descendants until A.D. 872. From the rudimentary thoughts of Tahir he
developed a theory of taxation which has affected modern economic
thought and even economic policies in the United States and elsewhere.
This
paper attempts to give Ibn Khaldun his forgotten and long overdue
credit and to place him properly within the history of economic thought.
He was preceded by a variety of economic but elemental ideas to which
he gave substance and depth. Centuries later these same ideas were
developed by the Mercantilists, the commercial capitalists of the
seventeenth century-Sir William Petty (A.D. 1623-1687), Adam Smith (A.D.
1723-1790), David Ricardo (A.D. 1772-1823), Thomas R. Malthus (A.D.
1766-1834), Karl Marx (A.D. 1818-1883), and John Maynard Keynes (A.D.
1883-1946), to name only a few-and finally by contemporary economic
theorists.
Labor Theory of Value, Economics of Labor, Labor as the Source of Growth and Capital Accumulation
With
the exception of Joseph A. Schumpeter, who discovered Ibn Khaldun's
writings only a few months before his death, Joseph J. Spengler, and
Charles Issawi, major Western economists trace the theory of value to
Adam Smith and David Ricardo because they attempted to find a reasonable
explanation for the paradox of value. According to Adam Smith and as
further developed by David Ricardo, the exchange value of objects is to
be equal to the labor time used in its production. On the basis of this
concept, Karl Marx concluded that "wages of labour must equal the
production of labour" and introduced his revolutionary term surplus
value signifying the unjustifiable reward given to capitalists, who
exploit the efforts of the labor class, or the proletariat. Yet it was
Ibn Khaldun, a believer in the free market economy, who first introduced
the labor theory of value without the extensions of Karl Marx.
According
to Ibn Khaldun, labor is the source of value. He gave a detailed
account of his labor theory of value, presenting it for the first time
in history. It is worth noting that Ibn Khaldun never called it a
"theory," but had skillfully presented it (in volume 2 of Rosenthal
translation) in his analysis of labor and its efforts. Ibn Khaldun's
contribution was later picked up by David Hume in his Political
Discourses, published in 1752: "Everything in the world is purchased by
labour."7 This quotation was even used by Adam Smith as a footnote.
"What is bought with money or with goods is purchased by labour, as much
as what we acquire by the toil of our body. That money or those goods
indeed save us this toil. They contain the value of a certain quantity
of labour which we exchange for what is supposed at the time to contain
the value of an equal quantity. The value of any commodity, therefore,
to the person who possesses it, and who means not to use or consume it
himself, but to exchange it for other commodities, is equal to the
quantity of labour which it enables him to purchase or command. Labour,
therefore, is the real measure of the exchangeable value of all
commodities." If this passage which was published in A.D. 1776 in Adam
Smith's major work, is carefully analyzed, one can find its seeds in Ibn
Khaldun's Prolegomena (The Muqaddimah). According to Ibn Khaldun, labor
is the source of value. It is necessary for all earnings and capital
accumulation. This is obvious in the case of craft. Even if earning
"results from something other than a craft, the value of the resulting
profit and acquired (capital) must (also) include the value of the labor
by which it was obtained. Without labor, it would not have been
acquired."
Ibn Khaldun divided all earnings into
two categories, ribh (gross earning) and kasb (earning a living). Ribh
is earned when a man works for himself and sells his objects to others;
here the value must include the cost of raw material and natural
resources. Kasb is earned when a man works for himself. Most translators
of Ibn Khaldun have made a common mistake in their understanding of
ribh. Ribh may either mean a profit or a gross earning, depending upon
the context. In this instance, ribh means gross earning because the cost
of raw material and natural resources are included in the sale price of
an object.
Whether ribh or kasb, all earnings are
value realized from human labor, that is, obtained through human
effort. Even though the value of objects includes the cost of other
inputs of raw material and natural resources, it is through labor and
its efforts that value increases and wealth expands, according to Ibn
Khaldun. With less human effort, a reversal to an opposite direction may
occur. Ibn Khaldun placed a great emphasis on the role of "extra
effort," which later became known as "marginal productivity," in the
prosperity of a society. His labor effort theory gave a reason for the
rise of cities, which, as his insightful analysis of history indicated,
were the focal points of civilizations.
Whereas
labor may be interpreted from Ibn Khaldun's ideas as both necessary and
sufficient conditions for earnings and profit, natural resources are
only necessary. Labor and its effort lead to production, which is in
turn used for an exchange through barter or through the use of money,
that is, gold and silver. The process therefore creates incomes and
profits which a man derives from a craft as the value of his labor after
having deducted the cost of raw material. Long before David Ricardo
published his significant contribution to the field of economics in
1817, The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Ibn Khaldun gave
the original explanation for the reasons behind the differences in
labor earnings. They may be attributed to differences in skills, size of
markets, location, craftsmanship or occupation, and the extent to which
the ruler and his governors purchase the final product. As a certain
type of labor becomes more precious, that is, if the demand for it
exceeds its available supply, its earnings must rise.
High
earnings in one craft attract others to it, a dynamic phenomenon which
will eventually lead to an increase in its available supply and
consequently lower profits. This principle explains Ibn Khaldun's
original and insightful analysis of long-term adjustments within
occupations and between one occupation and another. However, this point
of view was attacked by John Maynard Keynes in his famous statement that
in the long run we are all dead. Nevertheless, Ibn Khaldun's analysis
has not only proved to be historically correct but has also constituted
the core thinking of classical economists.
Ibn
Khaldun succinctly observed, explained, and analyzed how earnings in one
place may be different from another, even for the same profession.
Earnings of judges, craftsmen, and even beggars, for example, are
directly related to each town's degree of affluence and standard of
living, which in themselves are to be achieved through the fruits of
labor and the crystallization of productive communities. Adam Smith
explained differences in labor earnings by comparing them in England and
in Bengal along the same lines of reasoning given by Ibn Khaldun four
centuries earlier as he compared earnings in Fez with those of Tlemcen.
It was Ibn Khaldun, not Adam Smith, who first presented the contribution
of labor as a means of building up the wealth of a nation, stating that
labor effort, increase in productivity, and exchange of products in
large markets are the main reasons behind a country's wealth and
prosperity. Inversely, a decline in productivity could lead to the
deterioration of an economy and the earnings of its people. "A large
civilization yields large profits [earnings] because of' the large
amount of [available] labor which is the cause of [profit]."
It was also Ibn Khaldun, long before Adam Smith, who made a strong case for a free economy and for freedom of choice.
Among
the most oppressive measures, and the ones most deeply harming society,
is the compelling of subjects to perform forced work unjustly. For
labour is a commodity, as we shall show later, in as much as incomes and
profits represent value of labour of their recipients...nay most men
have no source of income other than their labour. If, therefore, they
should be forced to do work other than that for which they have been
trained, or made to do forced work in their own occupation, they would
lose the fruit of their labour and be deprived of the greater part, nay
of the whole, of their income.
To maximize both
earnings and levels of satisfaction, a man should be free to perform
whatever his gifted talents and skilled abilities dictate. Through
natural talents and acquired skills, man can freely produce objects of'
high quality, and, often, more units of labor per hour.
Demand, Supply, Prices, and Profits
In
addition to his original contribution to the economics of labor, Ibn
Khaldun introduced and ingeniously analyzed the interplay of several
tools of economic analysis; such is demand, supply, prices, and profits.
Demand
for an object is based on the utility of acquiring it and not
necessarily the need for it. Utility is therefore the motive force
behind demand. It creates the incentives for consumer spending in the
marketplace. Ibn Khaldun had therefore planted the first seed of modern
demand theory, which since been developed and expanded by Thomas Robert
Malthus, Alfred Marshall, John Hicks, and others. As a commodity in
demand attracts increased consumer spending, both the price and the
quantity sold are increased. Similarly, if the demand for certain crafts
decreases, its sales fall and consequently its price is reduced.
Demand
for a certain commodity also depends upon the extent to which it will
be purchased by the state. The king and his ruling class purchase much
larger quantities than any single private individual is capable of
purchasing. A craft flourishes when the state buys its product. With his
ingenious analytical mind, Ibn Khaldun had further discovered the
concept known in modern economic literature as "derived demand." "Crafts
improve and increase when the demand for their products increases."
Demand for a craftsman is therefore derived from the demand for his
product in the marketplace.
As is commonly known,
modern price theory states that cost is the backbone of supply theory.
It was Ibn Khaldun who first examined analytically the role of the cost
of production on supply and prices. In observing the differences between
the prices of foodstuffs produced in fertile land and of that produced
in poor soils, he traced them mainly to the disparity in the cost of
production.
[In] the coastal and hilly regions,
whose soil is unfit for agriculture, (inhabitants) were forced to apply
themselves to improving the conditions of those fields and plantations.
This they did by applying valuable work and manure and other costly
materials. All this raised the cost of agricultural production, which
costs they took into account when fixing their price for selling. And
ever since that time Andalusia has been noted for its high prices
....The position is just the reverse in the land of the Berbers. Their
land is so rich and fertile that they do not have to incur any expenses
in agriculture; hence in that country foodstuffs are cheap.
Besides
individual and state demand and cost of production, Ibn Khaldun
introduced other factors which affect the price of goods or services,
namely, the degree of affluence and the prosperity of districts, the
degree of concentration of the wealthy, and the degree of customs duties
being levied on middlemen and traders. The direct functional
relationship between income and consumption as presented by Ibn Khaldun
paved the road to the theory of consumption function as a cornerstone of
Keynesian economics.
Ibn Khaldun also made an
original contribution in his concept of profits. In economic literature,
a theory of profit as a reward for undertaking risk in a future of
uncertainties is generally attributed to Frank Knight, who published his
ideas in 1921. There is no doubt that Frank Knight substantially
advanced a well-established theory of profit. Nevertheless, it was Ibn
Khaldun, not Frank Knight, who originally planted the seed of this
theory: "Commerce means the buying of merchandise and goods, storing
them, and waiting until fluctuation of the market brings about an
increase in the prices of (these goods). This is called profit (ribh)."
In another context, Ibn Khaldun stated again the same idea: "Intelligent
and experienced people in the cities know that it is inauspicious to
hoard grain and to wait for high prices, and that the profit (expected)
may be spoiled or lost through (hoarding)." Profit is therefore a reward
for undertaking a risk. In the face of future uncertainties, a
risk-bearer may very well lose instead of gain. Similarly, profits or
losses may accrue as a result of speculation which is carried out by
profit-seekers in the marketplace. To maximize profits, Ibn Khaldun
introduced a gospel for traders, "Buy cheap and sell dear," which has
been widely quoted ever since. In his translation of the Muqaddimah of
Ibn Khaldun, Franz Rosenthal stated in a footnote, "In 1952 a book by
Frank V. Fischer appeared, entitled Buy LowSell High: Guidance for the
General Reader in Sound Investment Methods and Wise Trade Techniques."
If
Ibn Khaldun's gospel is applied to cost analysis, it becomes obvious
that profit may be increased, even for a given price of a final product,
when one reduces the cost of raw material and other inputs used in
production by buying them at a discount or, in general, at a low price
even from distant markets, as he indicated in his account of benefits of
foreign trade. Nevertheless, Ibn Khaldun concluded that both
excessively low prices and excessively high prices are disruptive to
markets. It is therefore advisable that states not hold prices
artificially low through subsidies or other methods of market
intervention. Such policies are economically disastrous because the
low-priced goods will disappear from the market and there will be no
incentive for suppliers to produce and sell whenever their profits are
adversely affected. Ibn Khaldun also concluded that excessively high
prices will not be compatible with market expansion. As the high-priced
goods sell less in the market, the policy of excessively high pricing
becomes counterproductive and disrupts the flow of goods in markets. Ibn
Khaldun had thus laid down the foundations of ideas which later led to
the formulation of disequilibrium analysis. He also cited several
factors affecting the upward general price level, such as increase in
demand, restrictions of supply, and increase in the cost of production,
which includes a sales tax as one of the components of a total cost.
After his analysis of what stimulates overall demand in it growing
economy, Ibn Khaldun stated the following:
Because
of the demand for (luxury articles), they become customary, and thus
come to be necessities. In addition, all labor becomes precious in the
city, and the conveniences become expensive, because there are many
purposes for which then, are in demand in view of the prevailing luxury
and because the government makes levies on market and business
transactions. This is reflected in the sales prices. Conveniences,
foodstuffs, and labor thus become very expensive. As a result, the
expenditures of the inhabitants increase tremendously in proportion to
the civilization of (the city). A great deal of money is spent. Under
these circumstances, (people) need a great deal of money for
expenditures, to procure the necessities of life for themselves and
their families, as well as all other requirements.
As
to the impact of restricted supply on the price level, Ibn Khaldun
summed it up thus: "When goods are few and rare, their prices go up."
By
carefully reading the above two passages, it becomes obvious that Ibn
Khaldun discovered what is now known as cost-push and demand-pull causes
of inflationary pressures. In fact, he was the first philosopher in
history who systematically identified factors affecting either the price
of a good or the general price level.
Macroeconomics, Growth, Taxes, Role of Governments, and Money
In
macroeconomics, Ibn Khaldun laid the foundations of what John Maynard
Keynes called "aggregate effective demand," the multiplier effect and
the equality of income and expenditure.25 When there is more total
demand as population increases, there is more production, profits,
customs, and taxes. The upward cycle of growth continues as civilization
flourishes and a new wave of total demand is created for the crafts and
luxury products. "The value realized from them increases, and, as a
result, profits are again multiplied in the town. Production there is
thriving even more than before. And so it goes with the second and third
increase." People's "wealth, therefore, increases and their riches
grow, the customs and ways of luxury multiply, and all the various kinds
of crafts are firmly established among them." The concept of the
multiplier was later developed and expanded by several economists, in
particular by John Maynard Keynes. However, it was discovered for the
first time in history by Ibn Khaldun.
Modern
national income accounts were also developed and expanded using the
equality of income and expenditures. Expenditures of one citizen are
income to others; therefore total expenditures are equal to total
incomes. This equality was first discovered by Ibn Khaldun. In fact, he
used both terms as synonymous to one another after having established
the equality between them. "Income and expenditure balance each other in
every city. If the income is large, the expenditure is large, and vice
versa. And if both income and expenditure are large, the inhabitants
become more favourably situated, and the city grows."
Ibn Khaldun introduced the pioneering theory of growth based on capital accumulation through man's efforts.
(Man)
obtains (some profits) through no efforts of his own, as, for instance,
through rain that makes the fields thrive, and similar things. However,
these things are only contributory. His own efforts must be combined
with them, as will be mentioned. (His) profits will constitute his
livelihood, if they correspond to his necessities and needs. They will
be capital accumulation it they are greater than (his needs)."
Ibn
Khaldun gave his account of the stages of economic development, from
nomadic to agricultural to more "cooperation in economic matters" which
occur through an expansion of a town to a city, where demand increases
and skilled labor congregates and expands production both ill quantity
and in "refinement." Economic growth continues so long as there is an
extra effort which creates capital accumulation, which in turn, combined
with effort, leads to more production and the development of crafts in
the cities. As was presented earlier, wealth expands through labor and
its efforts, whereas with less human effort there may occur a reversal
to stagnation, followed by a downward trend in people's standard of
living.
Governments play an important role in
growth and in the country's economy in general through their purchases
of goods and services and through their fiscal policy of taxation and
expenditures. Governments may also provide an environment of incentives
for work and prosperity or, inversely, a system of oppression which is
ultimately self-defeating. Even though Ibn Khaldun regards governments
as inefficient, "not so much calculation" is carried out by them of what
is contemporarily known as cost and benefit; they still play an
important role in the country's economy through their big purchases.
Government expenditures stimulate the economy by increasing incomes,
which are further hiked through a multiplier effect. However, if the
king hoards the amount he collects in taxes, business slackens and the
economic activities of the state are adversely affected through the
multiplier effect. In addition to its welfare program for the poor, the
widows, the orphans, and the blind, provided there is no overburden for
the treasury, the government should spend its tax revenue wisely to
improve conditions of its "subjects, to safeguard their rights and to
preserve them from harm."
Ibn Khaldun was the
first major contributor to tax theory in history. He is the philosopher
who shaped the minds of several rulers throughout history. More recently
his impact was evident on John F. Kennedy and later on Ronald Reagan.
"Our true choice is not between tax reduction on the one hand and
avoidance of large federal deficits on the other. An economy stilled by
restrictive tax rates will never produce enough revenue to balance the
budget, just as it will never produce enough jobs or enough profits."
John F. Kennedy said that back in 1962, when he was asking for a tax
decrease, a cut in tax rates across the board. But when John Kennedy
said those words, he was echoing the words of Ibn Khaldun, a Muslim
philosopher back in the fourteenth century, who said the following: "At
the beginning of the dynasty taxation yields large revenues from small
assessments. At the end of the dynasty taxation yields small revenue
from large assessments….This is why we had to have the tax program as
well as the budget cuts, because budget cuts, yes, would reduce
government spending."
According to Ibn Khaldun,
tax revenues of the ruling dynasty increase because of business
prosperity, which flourishes with easy, not excessive taxes. He was
therefore the first in history to lay the foundation of a theory for the
optimum rate of taxation, a theory which has even affected contemporary
leading advocates of supply-side economics such as Arthur Laffer and
others. The well-known Laffer curve is nothing but a graphical
presentation of the theory of taxation developed by Ibn Khaldun in the
fourteenth century.
"When tax assessments and
imposts upon the subjects are low, the latter have the energy and desire
to do things. Cultural enterprises grow and increase, because the low
taxes bring satisfaction. When cultural enterprises grow, the number of
individual imposts and assessments mount. In consequence, the tax
revenue, which is the sum total of the individual assessments,
increases"; whereas with large tax assessments, incomes and profits are
adversely affected, resulting, in the final analysis, in a decline in
tax revenue. Ibn Khaldun made a strong case against any government
attempt to confiscate or otherwise affect private property. Governments'
arbitrary interferences in man's property result in loss of incentives,
which could eventually lead to a weakening of the state. Expropriation
is self-defeating for any government because it is a form of oppression,
and oppression ruins society.
In macroeconomics
Ibn Khaldun also contributed to the theory of money. According to him,
money is not a real form of wealth but a vehicle through which it can be
acquired. He was the first to present the major functions of money as a
measure of value, a store of value and a "numeraire." "The two mineral
'stones,' gold and silver as the (measure of) value for all capital
accumulations ... [are] considered treasure and property. Even if under
certain circumstances, other things are acquired, it only for the
purpose of ultimately obtaining [them]. All other things are subject to
market fluctuations from which (gold and silver) are exempt. They are
the basis of profit, property and treasure." The real form of wealth is
not money, however; wealth is rather created or otherwise transformed
through labor in the form of capital accumulation in real terms. It was,
therefore, Ibn Khaldun who first distinguished between money and real
wealth, even though he realized that the latter may he acquired by the
former. Yet money plays a much more efficient role than barter in
business transactions in a society where man exchanges the fruits of his
labor, whether in the form of goods or of services, with another to
satisfy the needs which he cannot fulfill alone on his own. Money also
facilitates the flow of goods from one market to another, even across
the border of countries.
Foreign Trade
Ibn
Khaldun also contributed to the field of international economics.
Through his perceptive observations and his analytical mind, he
undoubtedly shed light on the advantages of trade among nations. Through
foreign trade, according to Ibn Khaldun, people's satisfaction,
merchants' profits, and countries' wealth are all increased.
The
merchant who knows his business will travel only with such goods as are
generally needed by rich and poor, rulers and commoners alike. (General
need) makes for a large demand for his goods...it is more advantageous
and more profitable for the merchants' enterprise... (that he will be
able to take advantage of) market fluctuations, if he brings goods from a
country that is far away...merchandise becomes more valuable when
merchants transport it from one country to another.
The
italicized word, valuable, indicates Ibn Khaldun's perception of the
gains of trade. If a good becomes more valuable by being transported
from country A to country B and still sells at a profit in B after the
cost of transportation and all other costs are taken into account, then
it is (1) cheaper than the same good produced internally, (2) of better
quality, or (3) a totally new product. If the foreign good is cheaper
than that produced internally, foreign trade will serve to economize
labor and other resources by having them diverted from the high-cost
good which cannot face competition to other low-cost products. The
resources which are saved from this process of diversion may be used to
produce other goods or may add another layer of capital accumulation.
Foreign trade may therefore contribute positively to the country's level
of income as well as to its level of growth and prosperity. If the
foreign good is of a better quality than that produced internally, the
imported good will add to the level of satisfaction of those who
purchase it. In the meantime, internal producers facing the competitive
high-quality product must attempt to improve their production or accept a
reduction in their sales and revenues. There will be a welfare gain in
either case: a rise in the quality of internal products or a diversion
of resources from the production of a high-cost good to a low-cost good,
as in the first case. In the last case, when the imported good is a
totally new product, the welfare gain from foreign trade may be
expressed in terms of an increase in the level of satisfaction of those
who purchase it or in terms of an increase in quantity or quality of
production of other goods if the imported item is a new tool or a
modification of an existing one. Furthermore, an introduction of a
totally new product through foreign trade may attract internal
producers, if it is feasible, to produce it once they are capable to
compete with the foreign product.
Ibn Khaldun was
conscious of what was later termed the "opportunity cost." Applying
valuable labor to improving poor soils means that the labor could have
been better used in the production of other goods. Resources in general
should be put to the best possible use. Otherwise there will be a cost
which will surface in a loss in value. Foreign trade provides further
incentives in the attempts to optimize the use of labor and other
natural resources.
Ibn Khaldun's originality in
his perceptive observations and analysis of foreign trade deserves
proper recognition in the field of international economics. The subject
of gains from trade has been substantially developed and expanded, in
particular, since the publication of Political Discourses by David Hume
in 1752. But the first original seed of the subject was planted by Ibn
Khaldun four centuries earlier.
Ibn Khaldun and Adam Smith
In
spite of Ibn Khaldun's overall contribution to the field of economics,
it is Adam Smith who has been widely called the "father of economics."
Schumpeter's view of Smith's economics is more critical than admiring.
"Personally, I do not share such a view, for I still consider Adam Smith
one of the great philosophers who has significantly contributed to the
field of economics even by having been a mere collector of previous
economic thoughts. He eloquently presented these ideas in detail in an
excellent new form and style. Nevertheless, by comparison, Ibn Khaldun
was far more original than Adam Smith, in spite of the fact that the
former had also restructured and built upon foundations laid down before
him, such as Plato's account of specialization, Aristotle's analysis of
money, and Tahir Ibn al-Husayn's treatment of government's role. Still,
it was Ibn Khaldun who founded the original ideas in numerous areas of
economic thought.
Despite Ibn Khaldun's
contributions, some economic ideas as well as some economic philosophy
of the freedom of choice, as presented above, were later attributed to
Adam Smith without giving due credit to the original thinker Ibn
Khaldun. "Smith's great economic treatise contains both his 'preaching'
of the 'gospel' of economic liberalism, i.e., economic freedom for all
individuals."39 Since there is such a striking similarity in the
economic thought of Ibn Khaldun and of Adam Smith, it must be left to
the economic historian to ascertain direct or indirect links between
these two great thinkers who were four centuries apart. However, I would
like to suggest some possible and likely points of contact. Even though
Adam Smith did not explicitly refer to Ibn Khaldun's contributions, it
may well be argued that there were several channels through which he may
have encountered the latter's pioneering and original economic thought.
Adam
Smith graduated from Glasgow University, where he was influenced by his
teacher Francis Hutcheson, who was in turn affected by Antony Ashley
Cooper, known as Lord Shaftesbury in the late seventeenth century and
early eighteenth century, and other philosophers who were concerned with
"liberal enlightenment," all of whom may have been directly or
indirectly affected by Ibn Khaldun's thought. After his graduation, Adam
Smith devoted six years to research at Oxford University's library,
where he may have been exposed to Ibn Khaldun's contributions even
without having been aware of the author's name. It was not uncommon in
early times that ideas were circulated, discussed, and delivered from
one generation to another without the name of an author. Furthermore,
ever since the Crusades, which lasted from the eleventh to the
thirteenth centuries, most Western philosophers attempted to discount
the impact of Muslim scholars through a multiplicity of approaches,
which included using Muslim ideas without mentioning the name of a
Muslim author. The protracted war waged by the Crusaders to capture the
Holy Land from the Muslims created a strong antagonistic feeling, well
embedded in the Western mind, from which Western scholars were not
immune and which lasted for centuries, probably until modern times.
Another possible channel through which Adam Smith may have been directly
or indirectly exposed to Ibn Khaldun's economic thought was through his
tour of Europe. During this tour he encountered Quesnsay, other
Physiocrats in Paris, and other European intellectuals who may have been
influenced by Ibn Khaldun in one way or another.
Adam
Smith could also have been exposed to the economic contributions of Ibn
Khaldun through the dominant influence of the Ottoman Empire. Ever
since the Ottoman Empire rose in the fourteenth century-and vastly
extended its boundaries at its peak in the sixteenth century to include
much of southeast Europe, southwest Asia, and northern Africa-a new
bridge was erected linking intellectuals in the Continent with their
counterparts in the vast territories of the empire, of which Egypt
became a part in 1517. It was in Egypt that Ibn Khaldun spent the latter
part of his life revising manuscripts of his works which he had
originally completed in Tunis in November of 1377. His thoughts were
then transmitted from one generation to another, from one century to
another, and from one country to another. Influenced by Ibn Khaldun's
idea that craftsmen and industrialists play a significant role in a
country's growth, prosperity, and power, Sultan Selim 1, after having
successfully extended his domain of influence over Egypt in 1517, took
back with him from Cairo to Constantinople the best-known artisans at
that time. In modern terminology, this was a case of a "transfer of
technology."
The impact of Ibn Khaldun was
extensive and profound, not only in the minds of some rulers and
statesmen, but also among intellectuals and educators long before his
books were even translated into other languages, In response to great
interest in his works, his books were finally translated to the Turkish
language in 1730, exactly forty-six years before the publication of Adam
Smith's The Wealth of Nations.
Concluding Remarks
Even
if Adam Smith was not directly exposed to Ibn Khaldun's economic
thoughts, the fact remains that they were the original seeds of
classical economics and even modern economic theory. Ibn Khaldun had not
only been well established as the father of the field of sociology, but
he had also been well recognized in the field of history, as the
following passage from Arnold Toynbee indicates:
In
his chosen field of intellectual activity [Ibn Khaldun] appears to have
been inspired by no predecessors ... and yet, in the Prolegomena ... to
his Universal History he has conceived and formulated a philosophy of
history which is undoubtedly the greatest work of its kind that has yet
been created by any mind in any time or place.
Through
his great sense and knowledge of history, together with his microscopic
observations of men, times, and places, Ibn Khaldun used an insightful
empirical investigation to analyze and produce original economic
thought. He left a wealth of contributions for the first time in history
in the field of economics. He clearly demonstrated breadth and depth in
his coverage of value and its relationship to labor; his analysis of
his theory of capital accumulation and its relationship to the rise and
fall of dynasties; his perceptions of the dynamics of demand, supply,
prices, and profits; his treatment of the subjects of money and the role
of governments; his remarkable theory of taxation, and other economic
subjects. His unprecedented contributions to the overall field of
economics should make him, Ibn Khaldun, the father of economics.
(Dr. Ibrahim M. Oweiss/Islamic World.net)
---
Consultant-Speaker-Motivator: www.ahmad-sanusi-husain.com
Alfalah Consulting - Kuala Lumpur : www.alfalahconsulting.com
Islamic Investment Malaysia: www.islamic-invest-malaysia.com
Pelaburan Unit Amanah Islam: www.unit-amanah-islam.com
Pelaburan Unit Amanah Islam: www.unit-amanah-islam.com
No comments:
Post a Comment